The following is the detailed response we have submitted to the FCC on it's NPRM 14-28 Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet (aka Net Neutrality proposals).
Response to the FCC NPRM on Open Internet prepared by Richard Ma (tbma@comp.nus.edu.sg) and Vishal Misra (misra@cs.columbia.edu)
1.
Para. 1: From the first sentence, the proposed
rulemaking emphasizes “broadband investment and deployment”. It seems that the
scope is really limited to broadband or eyeball ISPs. We want to emphasize that
the net neutrality issues are not limited to broadband. Many core issues are
involved with transit ISP and content providers as well. When it mentions
“open”, does it mean “neutral”? If it is not “open”, is the current Internet
“closed”? It seems that “open” is not well-defined. We comment that “open”
should be defined more clearly.
2.
Para. 2: “What is the right public policy to
ensure that the Internet remains open?” Again, to answer this question, we
first need to be clear about the definition of “open”.
3.
Para. 3: The no-blocking rule is too limited. An
ISP could give extremely small amount of capacity for certain content traffic,
which does not block it; however, the resulting quality might be too poor for
users to make use of the content. “Commercially unreasonable actions” needs a
clear definition and interpretations.
4.
Para. 4: “the best ways to define, prevent … the
practices that threaten an open Internet”. We suggest that the openness should
be defined based on the level of market competition. Our work [1] has shown
that whether regulations are needed really depends on whether market competition
exists or not.
5.
Para. 6: In general, access ISPs do have
incentives to maximize their revenue by differentiating services, which might
or might not be beneficial for the end-users; however, this is different from
being “open” or not. There is a zero-sum game between the edge and access
providers, therefore, it ultimately is a profit sharing problem [3, 4]. With
respect to the second point, our recent work [2] studies paid prioritization on
edge providers and from a social welfare perspective, our results support the
use of priority-based pricing and service differentiation rather than imposing
net neutrality regulations. With respect to the third point, our work [1]
confirms that without market competition, a monopoly ISP does have incentives
to make free ordinary services “damaged good”; however, market competition
could avoid such a scenario.
6.
Para. 10: “First, we generally propose to retain
the definitions and scope of the 2010 rules.” We comment that the scope could
be broadened and the definition of “open” should be made more clearly. “Second,
… should enhance the transparency rule …” We agree with this which will enhance
the competition among the ISPs. “Third, … no-blocking rule … with a revised
rationale, in order to ensure that all end users and edge providers can enjoy
the use of robust, fast and dynamic Internet access.” It seems that the
proposed requirement is a lot more than a no-blocking requirement. “Fourth, …
to adhere to an enforceable legal standard of commercially reasonable practices
…, asking how harm can best be identified and prohibited and whether certain
practices, like paid prioritization, should be barred altogether.” Again, we
comment that a more clear definition of “commercially reasonable practice” is
needed. In our work [1], we show that paid prioritization does not harm user
welfare unless the access ISP is a monopoly which makes a lower-class service
“damaged good”. We suggest that a service comparison between the different
service classes can be used as a guideline to limit service differentiations.
In our recent work [5], we propose to limit the quality difference, rather than
the absolute quality level, to ensure the “commercial reasonable actions”. “Fifth,
… dispute resolution process”. Our prior work [3, 4] looked into the ISP
settlement issues and identify that the Shapley mechanism could be an ideal
mechanism to arbitrate disputes among interconnecting ISPs to maximize the
social welfare. This can be practically difficult so the correct approach
should be to increase competition at the access which obviates the need for any
dispute resolution.
7.
Para. 12: “consumers’ hunger for high-value
content”. Net neutrality could hurt when low-value content compete with
high-value content and reduce them via negative network effect, i.e.,
congestion. Allowing ISPs’ differentiation could prioritize high-value content
to end-users.
8.
Para 13: the original purpose is to “encourage
broadband deployment”. Too restrictive a policy will reduce the incentives of
broadband providers to deploy in suburban areas.
9.
Para 17: “stop blocking” is easy to achieve,
however, the real question is about service differentiation. Could we allow
ISPs to limit the throughput of certain applications? Maybe we could not let
ISPs to “actively” limit the throughput, but they could maintain different
service classes and let edge providers to choose the services. We proposed and
studied this type of “passive” service differentiation in our work [1, 2, 5],
and our results in general support ISPs to provide such differentiations as
long as enough market competition exists.
10. Para
18: it all boils down to the question whether the network management is
reasonable or not. By measuring the relative quality (throughput) between BT
traffic and other traffic, as proposed in [5], one could infer whether the
network management is reasonable. If we only look at the quality of BT traffic,
even it gets low throughput, it might be because the system is limited in
capacity and cannot support the demand (not because of ISP’s differentiation).
11. Para.
20: “nondiscrimination and transparency rules” We suggest that
nondiscrimination should be defined to allow passive service differentiation
[1, 2, 5], e.g., class-based service differentiation, under which content
providers get to choose what service to use.
12. Para.
21: we want to comment that the 2nd case of “blocking” is a special
case of the 3rd scenario of “unreasonable discriminating in
transmitting lawful network traffic”. We need a definition of “unreasonable
discrimination” and suggest use the quality difference in different services.
13. Para.
23: “… D.C. Circuit … grant the Commission affirmative authority to encourage
and accelerate the deployment of broadband capability to all Americans through,
among other things, measures that promote competition in the local
telecommunications market or remove barriers to infrastructure investment.” We
totally agree with this view. Based on the results of our work [1, 2], we
suggest that the FCC should promote competition rather than imposing
restrictive rules on ISPs. “the court struck down the anti-blocking and
anti-discrimination rules, explaining that the Commission had chosen an
impermissible mechanism … imposed per se common carriage requirements … ” Based
on our work [5], we suggest that the FCC should not impose strict service
“requirements” on the providers. However, they could impose rules to restrict
the quality difference among service classes. On the one hand, through this
type of regulation, it does not impose a common carriage requirement. On the
other hand, this type of regulation is also enforceable and provides ISPs
spaces to differentiate services.
14. Para.
26: we want to comment that certain passive service differentiation does not
necessarily mean “restricting edge providers’ ability to reach users …”. Our
prior work [1] showed that the “short-term incentive to limit openness” does
exist under a monopolistic market. However, if market competition is enough,
this behavior will reduce the market share of the ISPs. We also showed that under market competition,
ISPs will have incentives to differentiate services, resulting in an increase
in the social welfare.
15. Para.
27: “… any small costs of imposing the rules were outweighed by the positive
effect on network investment from the preservation of the openness that drives
the virtuous circle …”. We have mixed feelings on this. A strict rule might
reduce the investment incentives of access ISP to deploy capacity to rural
areas.
16. Para.
32: “tremendous growth in the online video markets … revenues from online video
services grew 175% from $1.86 to $5.12 billion …” This causes congestion and
unbalance in profit sharing, which reduces the investment incentives from
access ISPs. Our prior work [3, 4] on Shapley profit-sharing indicates that a
re-balancing is needed to compensate the access ISPs from the content side
ISPs. This can be achieved in two ways, either by paid-peering arrangements or
by increasing competition at the access.
17. Para.
33: we agree that competition should be encouraged; however, without incentives
for ISPs to do service differentiation, they might not have any incentives to
deploy infrastructure to rural areas. Also, natural monopoly exists in those
areas, because a 2nd provider is basically too expensive. Regulating
this natural monopoly could be different from regulating other ISPs; otherwise,
no ISPs will be willing to deploy infrastructures in rural areas.
18. Para. 34: we want to comment on the role of
the Internet’s openness in facilitating innovation, economic growth,
competition and broadband investment and deployment. Here, we have conflicting
roles of competition and broadband investment. Increasing competition on the
broadband side might reduce their incentives to invest, but encourage more
investments on the edge/content providers. However, lack of investment in
infrastructure will eventually hurt the whole ecosystem, innovation and
economic growth. We need to balance the different objectives. One solution is
to look at both broadband providers and edge providers as a whole Internet
supply chain, and think about the revenue/profit sharing among them, so as to
maximize the utility of the overall ecosystem. Under such a macro model, we
might allow broadband providers to differentiate services and charge edge
providers.
19. Para.
36: the scope of the market between broadband and end-users is limited. No
evidence exists for “pay-for-priority” on end-users. However, broadband is
doing that on the peering side.
20. Para.
37: voluntary subsidization could be a useful mechanism, where the broadband
still maintains a physically neutral network, while service differentiation is
maintained at a higher economic layer. Product differentiation is not uncommon
in other areas, e.g., first class airfare, student tickets, and etc. Our
on-going work [6] analyzes the subsidization competition among the content
providers when policy allows. Our preliminary results show that it could serve
a (physically) neutral and viable mechanism to attract investment incentives
for access ISPs. The danger is that new entrants in the edge provider market
might find it difficult to compete with established players with deeper
pockets.
21. Para
40: The European ISPs have to unbundle their local loops, which creates
competition among the providers. Thus, even when there is no policy to prohibit
ISPs to block traffic, competition will drive them not to hurt user welfare, if
such a blocking does so. This is supported by our public option work [1] and
the developments in the UK market [7]. On the other hand, the lack of
competition in the US (because of no local-loop unbundling) makes policy more
important. The problem is not about whether there are cases of blocking, but
whether competition is enough for users to choose providers in case one of them
is not satisfactory to the users.
22. Para
41: Again, the problem is related to the lack of competition. When AT&T is
the only provider and it lacks capacity, there might be a good reason (network
management, or economic) for it to restrict applications. It is difficult to
judge whether such a restriction is good or bad. Without such a restriction,
capacity-heavy application might affect the usage of other apps when the
wireless capacity is limited. When competition is there, users will have
choices to switch to another provider which might allow such apps, but probably
with poorer quality. In a monopoly case, regulation needs to be carefully
designed. If we want to guarantee a minimum service quality for apps, this
threshold might depend on the capacity of the provider and other factors.
Instead, we propose to limit the quality difference [5] among services rather
than putting an absolute guaranteed minimum service quality for the free
services.
23. Para
42: we do not agree that “the threat of …. Did not depend on … market power”.
In fact, that is the root cause. We have shown the impact of market power in
our work [1, 3].
24. Para
43: we do not agree that “the commission need not engage in a market power
analysis to justify its rules …”. “the
ability to block edge providers depended on “end users not being fully
responsive to the imposition of such restrictions””, we comment that
transparency is needed to make users to be aware of such restrictions. The
no-responsiveness could be because the restriction does not affect users’
welfare/utility much and switching to another provider is not necessary. The
real threat is that it matters to the users, but due to the lack of market
competition and user choices, the users have to stay with the current provider.
25. Para.
44: “broadband providers have incentives and the economic ability to limit
Internet openness …” we comment that broadband providers do not have a direct
incentive to limit openness, unless it is going to increase their
profit/revenue. In a competitive market, they won’t have such incentives if
users are sensitive to service quality. Also, broadband providers do not have
strong incentives to limit the openness on the end-user side, but have more
incentive to differentiate at the peering side with the edge providers, who
might have much larger profit margins compared to the access providers. The
changing market place, including the change in content, e.g. the rise of
Netflix and CDNs, has affected the broadband peering strategies greatly.
Technology-wise, it is not difficult to physically separate different capacities
along different routing paths. With the emerging Software Defined Networking (SDN)
approaches, ISPs might have stronger abilities to manage their network
resources to differentiate their peering relationships with other ISPs/CPs. Our
work [1] showed that by differentiate capacity at the CP-side, the ISP has
incentives to do so to increase revenue under a monopoly setting. In
particular, the ISP has incentives to make free/open class “damaged good” to
force CPs to use premium class and pay, which might hurt social welfare. We
showed that competition, e.g., the introduction of Public option, could solve
the problem. Justification for charging edge providers could be the basic
economic efficiency: capacity is limited, by differentiate high- and low-value
traffic, the ISP could provide higher welfare to users and CPs.
26. Para.
45: Transit ISPs use parameters in BGP routing protocol to choose different
routing paths. Access ISPs use public/private peering settings to control
traffic. On the user-side, mobile providers use data cap to control and price
traffic data. AT&T’s sponsored data plan introduces voluntary subsidization
from CPs to end-users for their over-cap traffic. As for the Comcast case, its
private peering practice might be used to exploit their monopoly market power
in the access market. Level3 data hints at that.
27. Para.
46: we do not have data to understand the switching costs. However, we support
that transparency to be given to users, so that they understand more of their
choices/options and improve the market competition.
28. Para.
47: “We seek comment on the state of competition in broadband Internet access
service, and its effect on providers’ incentives to limit openness.” We guess
many people will comment on the monopolistic status of Comcast. Our public
option work [1] showed that the monopoly has incentives to differentiate
service at the CP-side and show its incentives to make public peering “damaged
good”, which is claimed by Level3. Thus, we advocate a public option approach
to introduce competition, under which no regulation is needed to monopoly.
Otherwise, suitable regulation might be needed to regulate the monopoly. DSL’s
openness practice could incentivize high-speed broadband to differentiate CPs
less aggressive, although another high-speed provider’s competition will help
more.
29. Para.
48: needs more market data for market competition analysis.
30. Para.
49: as our study [1] showed, market competition is a key to whether regulation
is needed. We suggest that regulation should be closely coupled with market
power analysis.
31. Para.
50: “there are other economic theories …” 1) Shapley value for inter-ISP
settlement [3, 4], and 2) public option [1] for access ISP service
differentiation and competition, and 3) subsidization competition [6] among the
content providers. Also, on the value of the network, the exact form of n^2 or
n log n doesn’t matter - the important theoretical distinction is whether the
value of the network is a convex function of n or not - and both n^2 and
n log n satisfy convexity.
32. Para.
51: technically, access ISP might be able to block end-user traffic; however,
flow-based control is expensive and difficult for ISPs, and has little economic
incentives to do so. ISPs largely use public/private peering nowadays to
differentiate classes of traffic via inter-AS routing. The routing is currently
based on BGP protocol, a rough tool to do fine grain flow-level control. Thus,
we suggest the rules extend its scope to include inter-AS settlement and
peering relationships.
33. Para.
52: yes, ISPs could use traffic management tools. However, most practices are
simply macro-level private/peering relationships, where physical links are
separated/isolated and no active differentiations are needed for the traffic
flows.
34. Para.
59: “.. the rules were not intended “to affect existing arrangements for
network interconnection, including existing paid peering arrangements””, we
comment that the inter-connect agreement between the broadband and other
transit ISPs should be included within the scope, otherwise, less could be done
to limit the service differentiation done on the CP-side.
35. Para.
60: in general, a “specialized service” could be a prioritized service which
brings extra revenue for the ISP and its users. However, as we showed in our
work [1], ISPs might have incentives to make ordinary service “damaged good” so
as to force users to use specialized service and pay them. Thus, we might need
to impose conditions under which specialized service could be provided.
36. Para.
62: this is reasonable and useful to distinguish mobile and fixed service
providers, and based on their characteristics, e.g., cost structure and
capacity, to impose different regulations, e.g., different minimum requirement
for service and thresholds for service quality differences.
37. Para.
63-88: we general support the transparency in any aspect, as long as it’s
practically feasible. The main reason is that transparency could improve market
completion, under which strict regulations might not even be needed.
38. Para.
89-109: blocking is definitely undesirable for users and CPs. However, the D.C.
Circuit vacated the rule mainly because of the legal “common carriage”
requirement, which the ISPs might not be responsible for. We do not oppose the
proposed rule, however, it still does not have a legal justification and “a
clarification … does not preclude …” makes the rule almost non-enforcing. To
impose a minimum level of service is encouraging; however, the legal
justification is still missing and what this level to set needs further
thoughts.
39. Para.
90: “relationship between no-blocking and commercially reasonable rules”.
No-blocking is a special case of the later.
40. Para.
101: “we seek comment on how minimum level of access should be defined”. This
is important. Different type of ISPs should have different thresholds. Different
type of CPs might have different minimum requirements, although from a
regulatory and practical perspective, it is difficult to set different
requirements for each different CP. Furthermore, under sufficient competition,
we think even the minimum requirements are not needed.
41. Para.
104: we agree that the requirement should also be evolving based on the
changing characteristics of content and user expectations.
42. Para.
110-141: “Codifying an enforceable rule that is not common carriage per se”. D.C. rejected prior rule based on “(it) so
limited broadband providers’ control over edge providers’ transmissions that
[it] constituted common carriage per se.” from this perspective, I feel that a
requirement of minimum service requirement is still like imposing a “common
carriage” requirement on the ISPs, which does not have a legal justification
for the FCC (although it might have its economic justifications). Therefore, in
our work [5], we suggest a milder/weak, but enforceable rule, which restrict
the difference in service qualities of the different services provided by the
ISPs. If the ISP is really capacity constrained, then its premium service
quality cannot be high, unless its ordinary service has to be maintained at
certain level. The advantage is that it does not impose a fixed/hard
requirement on the ISPs, and the rule is flexible for different types of
providers, e.g., mobile provider might maintain lower QoS for ordinary (e.g.,
best-effort) and it premium service (e.g., 1Mbps), while high-speed broadband
can provide very high-quality premium service (e.g., 10Mbps), when its ordinary
service can guarantee already quite good service (e.g. 2Mbps). By imposing such
a relative regulation, it does not impose any hard requirement for ISPs to
fulfill. In comparison, minimum requirement rule read more like “you have to
become a common carriage first, so as to be qualified to differentiate
services”. Both have similarities and differences in terms of justifications
and practicality.
43. Para.
142-160: these are legal authority and considerations, not our expertise. We
suppose the rule needs to avoid imposing “common carriage” kind of regulations
to ISPs.
44. Para.
161-176: this is dispute resolution. We comment that our proposed Shapley value
mechanism can be used for inter-AS dispute resolution. However, it is more on
the peering side, not on the end-user side.
References
[1] Richard T. B. Ma and Vishal Misra. The Public Option: A Non-Regulatory Alternative to Network Neutrality.
IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking,
Volume 21, Issue 6, pp. 1866 - 1879, December, 2013.
[2] Jingjing Wang, Richard T. B. Ma and Dah Ming Chiu. Paid Prioritization and Its Impact on Net
Neutrality. Proceedings of IFIP
Networking Conference 2014.
[3] Richard T. B. Ma, Dah Ming Chiu, John C. S. Lui, Vishal
Misra and Dan Rubenstein. On Cooperative
Settlement Between Content, Transit and Eyeball Internet Service Providers.
IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking,
Volume 19, Issue 3, pp. 802 - 815, June, 2011.
[4] Richard T. B. Ma, Dah Ming Chiu, John C. S. Lui, Vishal
Misra and Dan Rubenstein. Internet
Economics: The Use of Shapley Value for ISP Settlement. IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking, Volume 18, Issue 3, pp. 775 -
787, June, 2010.
[5] Jing Tang and Richard T. B. Ma. Regulating Monopolistic ISPs without Neutrality. Proceedings
of IEEE International Conference on
Networking Protocols (ICNP) 2014.
[6] Richard T. B. Ma. Subsidization
Competition: Vitalizing the Neutral Internet. Working paper. http://arxiv.org/pdf/1406.2516v1.pdf.
[7] Thomas
Newton. ISP Traffic Management:
BT vs Virgin vs Sky vs TalkTalk vs EE. http://recombu.com/digital/news/isp-traffic-management-bt-sky-virgin-media-ee-talktalk_M11045.html
Most areas of the U.S. have at least a few high-speed internet options and more than likely a few dial-up options available. To find the services available in your area consult our list of providers and once you narrow the list down to the internet service providers (ISPs) in your general area, you can find what specific services are available in your exact location. Visit the Bundlesrus of an ISP and input your address or phone number into the search tool to pinpoint exactly internet plans are available in your area.
ReplyDeleteFibnet internet service
ReplyDeletesection-052cc37 Fibnet broadband internet Network Solutions from Fibnet Cloud Top of the line security to protect
your data Networking Fast, easy, and stable networking solution guaranteed Mobility High-speed mobile internet