Skip to main content

The Public Option: Municipal Broadband Access

The recent announcement of the Comcast acquisition of Time Warner Cable has caused quite a furore. Consumer advocates are worried that it will cause problems, higher prices, bad performance etc. The issue is it will lead to the creation of a giant monopoly. Comcast argues that it is not a monopoly and as it is Time Warner and Comcast do not compete in any market so it should make no difference anyway. There are two issues here: (a) first is the question why have Time Warner and Comcast, two giant corporations not competed anywhere yet? and, (b) the second and more important issue is not that of competition for cable service, which ostensibly Dish Networks also provides, but for Broadband access, where 19 of the top 20 metropolitan areas in the US will have only one choice for wired Broadband.

The merger/acquisition is not between two Cable companies, but that of wired Broadband ISPs that are virtual monopolies.

Our work, Richard T. B. Ma and Vishal Misra, The Public Option: a Non-regulatory Alternative to Network NeutralityIEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking, 2013, proposed a non-regulatory option to Network Neutrality that works for consumers. A presentation based on the work is available here. We developed a realistic equilibrium model for congestion on the Internet, taking into account content bandwidth demand, user patience levels and the impact of protocols like TCP.

Our analysis showed that if the Internet provider is a monopoly, it can hurt consumers in many ways. If Network Neutrality is not in place, ISPs can create scenarios that hurt both consumers as well as content providers, with the remedy being paying more revenue to the ISP. This revenue can be collected directly from the broadband subscribers, or by the content providers in the style of AT&T sponsored data. In either case, the extra costs will be passed on to the consumer.

The alternative is true competition with multiple providers, where consumers have options that they can instantly switch to (and for our arguments, a month qualifies as instantly). In fact, our work shows that if true competition exists with multiple providers, network neutrality does not benefit consumers and there is a case to be made for non-neutral ISP services, one size does not fit all. But only if there is true competition. A way to get more competition at the eyeball level for consumers is via something like local loop unbundling (LLU). LLU operators are prevalent in Europe where the broadband market does have healthy competition and lower rates than the US.

The other option is what we call The Public Option. The Public Option is an ISP that voluntarily implements Network Neutrality. Our work shows that the presence of the Public Option is good for social welfare - ISPs can implement non network-neutral policies if they desire, but the consumers and content providers do not lose out.

One of the possibilities that we laid out in our paper was that The Public Option be implemented via municipal broadband.

Our proposal is almost exactly what Susan Crawford has been advocating, like the municipal broadband effort in Massachusetts. As she spoke about in a recent talk, the concept has shown to be viable economically in Stockholm, via the Stokab project. Google fiber, while attractive, isn't going to be a real option for 99% of the nation. It will show what true broadband access is capable of (which the rest of the world is learning much faster than the US), but Google will never become a FTTH ISP.  Local bodies can provide an alternative, and we think The Public Option via municipal broadband is the way to go.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

The business of ZeroRating

ZeroRating conversations are dominating Network Neutrality issues these days, whether it is the FreeBasics controversy  in India, Binge On by T-Mobile, or Verizon's recent announcement of a plan similar to AT&T's sponsored data. Here are a few thoughts to consider about ZeroRating and why it makes no sense (to me). If ISPs Zero Rate content, somebody has to pay for the bandwidth. Suppose the Content provider pays for it. Then there is a pricing problem: ISPs cannot charge the content provider a price above the price they charge consumers. Suppose they charge consumers X per MB of data, and they charge content providers X+Y per MB of data. Then, for sufficient traffic where overheads are accounted for, it is cheaper  for content providers to send recharge coupons back directly to the customers who used their services. Long term, pricing above the consumer price is not sustainable. ISPs cannot  charge the content provider a price below  the price they cha...

A short tutorial on the Robust Synthetic Control python library, Part 1: counterfactuals

I have posted a couple of blogs on the powerful technique of (multidimensional) Robust Synthetic Control here and here . In this post I will give a short tutorial on how you can use mRSC to perform your own analysis using the python package my collaborator Jehangir has made available on github. This posting will be about counterfactual analysis. We will work with the canonical example of the synthetic control based counterfactual analysis of the impact California's Prop 99 . All the data and code is included in the github repository linked above. I will post the python code as run on a Jupyter Notebook, and the "tslib" library referenced above has been downloaded and is available. Preliminaries: importing the libraries. In [1]: import sys , os sys . path . append ( "../.." ) sys . path . append ( ".." ) sys . path . append ( os . getcwd ()) from matplotlib import pyplot as plt import matplotlib.ticker as ti...

mRSC: A new way to answer What Ifs and do time series prediction

Introduction What if the federal minimum wage is raised to 16 dollars an hour? What if Steve Smith bats at number 5 in the Ashes 2019 instead of number 3? What if Australian style gun laws were implemented in the USA - what would be the impact on gun related violence? What if Eden Hazard attacks today instead of winging in the midfield? "What if?” is one of the favorite questions that occupy minds, from sports fans to policymakers to philosophers. Invariably, there is no one answer to the What ifs and everyone remains convinced in their own alternate realities but a new wave of work has been looking at data-driven approaches to answer (at least a subset of) these What If questions. The mathematical tool of (Robust) Synthetic Control examines these What If questions by creating a synthetic version of reality and explore its evolution in time as a counterfactual to the actual reality. Recently, together with my collaborators Jehangir Amjad (MIT/Google) Devavra...